Example sentences of "[prep] future " in BNC.

  Next page
No Sentence
1 An obvious way to examine whether marking to the market in the presence of stochastic interest rates leads to a difference between futures and forward prices , is to compare actual futures and forward prices for the same asset .
2 ( See Chapter 2 for a list of differences between futures and forward markets . )
3 Twite ( 199Ob ) examined daily values of the Australian All Ordinaries index between 1983 and 1986 and found a significantly positive correlation between futures returns and the riskless rate of interest .
4 A study of the MMI by Chang , Loo and Chang ( 1990 ) analysed the difference between futures and forward prices using a test which differs from those proposed by Cox , Ingersoll and Ross ( 1981 ) .
5 It appears that the effect of marking to the market with stochastic interest rates is generally rather small , can vary as between futures ( depending on the sensitivity of their price to movements in interest rates ) and may also vary over time for the same future .
6 They demonstrate that when futures are indivisible , even if movements in futures prices can be predicted and interest rates are constant ( and so there is zero correlation between futures prices and interest rates ) , futures and forward prices will differ .
7 Thus the Cox , Ingersoll and Ross result is changed , and forward and futures prices will differ , even when there is zero correlation between futures prices and interest rates .
8 There is a close relationship between futures prices and spot prices , especially as the delivery date approaches .
9 There are two other explanations of the relationship between futures prices and expected future spot prices , one consistent with the backwardation relationship and the other consistent with the contango relationship .
10 The professional exams for futures dealers are hogwash as far as the directors of some firms are concerned .
11 Cox , Ingersoll and Ross ( 1981 ) have shown that , if riskless interest rates are certain ( and the other assumptions listed in Chapter 4 apply ) , despite the presence of marking to the market for futures contracts , futures and forward contracts have an identical price .
12 Thus , if the no-marking-to-the-market assumption is replaced with an assumption that riskless interest rates are certain , the no-arbitrage condition in Chapter 4 for futures prices still applies .
13 Modest and Sundaresan ( 1983 ) have shown that the no-arbitrage condition for futures on a geometric index is different from that for an arithmetic index .
14 The term y must be positive , and so the no-arbitrage price for futures on a geometric index is lower than for the corresponding arithmetic index .
15 While there is an exact no-arbitrage price for futures on geometric indices , it requires the calculation of y , and this may be difficult and may cause the arbitrage to be risky .
16 If marking to the market exists , this condition is not met for futures , and has been discussed above in connection with the no-marking-to-market assumption .
17 Although the regulatory systems for futures markets have generally prevented defaults , the probability of a default must always exist to some small ( and variable ) degree .
18 Thus , the omission of a default premium from the no-arbitrage condition is probably of little consequence for futures traded on established and well-regulated exchanges .
19 The derivation of the no-arbitrage condition for futures prices assumes that the value of the index is given .
20 If a rate of return could also be defined for futures markets , futures could then be treated as an additional asset in portfolio and capital market theories , and the concept and tests of market efficiency could also be extended , in a straightforward manner , to futures markets .
21 The security market line is usually stated in terms of rates of return but , as discussed in Section 7.1 , the notion of a rate of return for futures has proved problematic .
22 This avoids the problems of defining returns for futures contracts .
23 C it is shown that the demand for futures can be split into speculative and hedging components , and that it is rational for a risk-averse trader to speculate and hedge simultaneously in the same future .
24 Hemler and Longstaff ( 1991 ) used a general equilibrium model to derive a pricing equation for futures prices ( see Chapter 5.3.24 ) .
25 A number of empirical studies of the volatility-maturity relationship for futures , other than index futures , are summarized in Table 8.2 .
26 While this assumption is questionable for shares due to short selling difficulties , it is more acceptable for futures contracts .
27 Volatility for futures prices was measured as the square root of the absolute value of the natural logarithm of the daily price relatives , multiplied by 252 , that is , .
28 In April 22 traders were charged with illegal trading , and the Justice Department announced on Aug. 2 that a total of 46 traders had been indicted for futures fraud .
29 The RIE does escape the financial resources requirements which would apply to an ordinary authorised firm , but for futures exchanges , capital matters are in any case delegated to the London Clearing House .
30 Very few Account Executives ( AEs ) at DPR Futures knew anything beyond the most basic facts about futures .
  Next page